Neoliberalism at Work

Austerity: Why and for Whom?
Home | Globalization and the Corporatist State-jk | NEOLIBERALISM EXPOSED--jk | what is neoliberalism? | China Economy: insights on globalization | Globalization, consequences, China | Neoliberals and Global Social Democracy--GSD | Who Owns the Federal Reserve | Green Left: Europes political 3rd Party? | Austerity: Why and for Whom? | G20 Meeting & Debt Reduction--Naomi Klein | Anti-tariff spin in the media--article and rebuttal | NAFTA Super Highway | Neoliberals privatize SPYING

Austerity: Why and for Whom?

By Richard Wolff; In These Times 7/15/10 http://www.inthesetimes.com/article/6232/austerity_why_and_for_whom/

Richard D. Wolff is professor of Economics Emeritus, University of Massachusetts, Amherst, where he taught economics from 1973 to 2008. He is currently a Visiting Professor in the Graduate Program in International Affairs of the New School University, New York City. He also teaches classes regularly at the Brecht Forum in Manhattan.

Clearly, the global capitalist crisis that started in 2007 will be neither short nor shallow. The government rescue of the U.S. financial industry pumped enough extra money into the economy and sufficiently reduced interest rates to give banks and the stock market the heavily hyped “recovery” that started March 2009 and is now over.

What is worse, their recovery never reached much of the rest of the economy. Efforts to broaden the recovery or extend it beyond one limp year have failed. That failure cost Washington trillions in borrowed funds from lenders who now demand guarantees that those loans will be repaid to them with interest. Similar demands now confront many other governments who likewise borrowed heavily to cope with the crisis in their countries.

The guarantee demanded by lenders is “austerity.Lenders want governments to raise taxes or cut government spending or both. Governments will then have more money available to pay interest on loans and to repay those loans. Governments that fail to impose austerity will face higher interest on new and renewed loans or will be denied loans which would cripple those governments’ usual operations. Austerity is yet another extreme burden imposed on the global economy by the capitalist crisis (in addition to the millions suffering unemployment, reduced global trade, etc.).

Who are these lenders demanding austerity? The globally active financial enterprises—mostly banks that collapsed in the crisis and were rescued by their home governments—are, together, also major lenders to those governments. Banks own their own governments’ debts but also other governments’ debts. For example, major banks in France and Germany are among the Greek government’s chief creditors. US banks and related financial enterprises hold significant amounts of other governments’ debts and other nations’ banks own much US government debt.

Global capitalism’s 2007 crisis froze the credit system that sustains capitalist production. Private borrowers—enterprises and individuals—could no longer repay loans because their investments had generated too little and their incomes had failed to grow enough. Banks had failed to properly assess risks in deciding how much to lend to whom[1]. They therefore stopped lending to private borrowers because that had become too risky. As private borrowers defaulted and new lending atrophied, banks’ capital and their profits collapsed. The whole capitalist system ground toward a halt because credit became unavailable.

The only solution most leaders in capitalist countries could conceive was to unfreeze credit by having the government guarantee bank solvency, guarantee many private debts, invest massively in and lend to private banks, and become the ultimate borrower of a huge portion of loanable funds. Banks everywhere lent to governments because it had become unsafe to lend to almost anyone else. Governments everywhere used the borrowed money to rescue banks and other financial enterprises[2].

This peculiar “nationalization” of debt served capitalism by having the government temporarily function as the lender and borrower of last resort. Nationalization unfroze the credit system sufficiently to stop the crisis from collapsing global capitalism. Few policy-makers (and few others) in 2008 and early 2009 worried much about the consequences of so massively increasing government debts. The looming possible capitalist system collapse overwhelmed worry about any “longer run.”

The international banks that were rescued (from their own bad loans and investments) by governments now worry that governments they lent to won’t be able to repay those loans. Banks threaten to make further loans much more costly or even impossible unless those governments impose “austerity.[3] Most political leaders recognize that the banks’ threats, if carried out under their watch, would end their careers quickly and badly. All capitalists see in possible government defaults the specter of another credit freeze with terrifying ramifications for global capitalism. Still worse for those banks: governments in default would not likely be able to borrow again to rescue banks again.

Nearly all current political leaders of major capitalist countries responded positively to the banks’ demand for austerity (as in Canada’s recent G-20 meeting). This immediately raised a basic political conflict always simmering inside capitalism: who will pay increased taxes and who will suffer decreased government spending? Militants in Europe have already marched and struck against austerity as an unacceptable plan to make workers pay to fix capitalists’ crises; more general strikes are set in many European nations with a Europe-wide general strike now scheduled for September 29. Meanwhile, capitalists work with politicians to define as “reasonable in crisis times” austerity programs mixing both tax increases (chiefly on workers) and spending cuts (chiefly on workers).

An Athens trucker says, “Public employees here don’t work hard enough, so it is reasonable to cut their pay.” A Parisian clerk thinks it “reasonable to postpone the official retirement age a few years; we all live longer now.” A Minneapolis office worker agrees that it is “reasonable, in crisis times, to get by with fewer public services.” A New York laboratory technician supports a new tax on cell-phones as “probably reasonable; after all, people overuse them.” Remarkably, such notions of “reasonable” are silent about other possible and, to say the least, more “reasonable” forms of austerity.

Let’s consider some alternative “reasonable” kinds of austerity (i.e., austerity for others) and then question austerity itself. Serious efforts to collect income taxes from U.S.-based multinational corporations, especially those who use internal pricing mechanisms to escape U.S. taxation, would generate vast new federal revenues. The same applies to wealthy individuals. The U.S. has no federal property tax on holdings of stocks, bonds, and cash accounts (states and localities levy no such property taxes either).

If the federal government levied a 1 per cent tax on assets between $100,000 to 499,000, and 1.5 per cent on assets above $500,000, that would raise much new federal revenue (everyone’s first $100,000 could be exempted just as the existing U.S. income tax exempts the first few thousands of dollars of individual incomes). Exiting the Iraq and Afghanistan disasters would do likewise. Ending tax exemptions for super-rich private educational institutions (Harvard, Yale, etc.) and for religious institutions (church-goers would then need to pay the costs of their churches) would be among the many other such alternative “reasonable” austerity measures. Comparable alternatives apply—and are being struggled over—in other countries.

A capitalist system that generates so massive a crisis, spreads it globally, and then proposes mass austerity to “overcome” it has lost the right to continue unchallenged. Should we not be publicly debating whether America (and the world) might be better served by going beyond capitalism? Can we not learn from capitalism’s repeated cycles (failures) and change to a new, non-capitalist system? Having learned hard lessons from the first socialist attempts during the last century in Russia, China, and beyond, can we not rise to the challenge to make a new attempt that avoids their failures and builds on their strengths? When better than now?

 

Comments by jk.  For those who don’t learn from history, they live to repeat it.  See the detailed analysis of the great depression.  Secondly, Naomi Klein points out that what is coming is a rerun of what she calls the Pinochet solution, in her The Rise of Disaster Capitalism. Finally, the decline that the bottom 95% is experiencing in their standard of living--contrary to the expansion of productivity averaging a compounded over 2% per year since the 1960s--is because the financial community in those years has grown from 15% of the GDP to over 46%, and they only produce debt payments.  Assuming Ms. Klein is right, the world is about to undergo an implosion following the Pinochet pattern of Argentina.  The call for austerity follows that pattern. 

There is another solution, but government cannot stand up to those who fund their elections.  It is the Roosevelt fix, put money into the hands of those who buy things, the bottom 95%. This didn’t happen until, what Teddy Roosevelt called the shadow government, many of them called for this solution.  These moguls of business feared a populist revolution.  We have a long way to go.    

 

 

 



[1]   This point I see from a different prospective--assessment of risk was not the cause.  Namely, one, the huge expansion of currency force banks to find new sources for their loans.  This is because the directors of the banks are driven to show profits comparable to those of other banks--otherwise the corporate stocks perform among the worst in their sector.  Job performance is measured short-term.  Once the secure loans were exhausted they proceeded to those of greater risk.  And they loans because the panic in finance greatly increased the risk.--jk. 

[2]  Close (restated with clarity):  governments don’t simply print money.  They sell t-bills mainly to the banks, and then the governments turned around with this created money and loaned it back to the banks.  Most often this was done without interest or strings; viz., welfare for the banks.  The banks benefited a second way, by having bought the t-bills; they are recipients of interest payments from the government--jk. 

[3] Governments don’t pay off t-bill as they mature.  They simply sell more t-bills to replace the matured ones.  If banks won’t buy the t-bills at the current low interest, the interest paid on the new ones must be raised.  This will further increase the percentage of tax revenues given to the holders of t-bills.  In 2010 those interest payments amounted to over $450 billion-jk. 

Enter supporting content here

Teddy Roosevelt's advice that, "We must drive the special interests out of politics. The citizens of the United States must effectively control the mighty commercial forces which they have themselves called into being. There can be no effective control of corporations while their political activity remains."